China Policy Journal Volume 1, Number 1, Fall 2018 | Page 15

China Policy Journal establishment of a pollution information-management system, pollutant measurement, pollution-loads calculation, monitor-receiving water bodies, and so forth directly lower the regional environmental authorities’ efficiency and weaken the system’s influence and power. 2.2.3. Revenue Issue The water-pollutant discharge-fee system generates revenue and should be earmarked for environmental expenditures rather than for departmental expenditures. The water-pollution discharge fee is collected by local environmental authorities. The 2003 pollution discharge-fee-management regulation stipulates that it is to be used as a specific environmental protection fund, covering the major pollution-source-control program, the regional pollution-prevention program, the new technology-application program, and other pollution-control programs. In theory, local environmental protection bureaus only act as fee-collection units, of which the management fee should not be included in the pollution-discharge fee, though departments’ management funding is in fact heavily reliant on the pollution-discharge fee. The connection between revenue and expenditure reflects the contradiction in the design of the fee system’s mechanism. In this collection mode and in view of departmental interests, it is not strange that local environmental-protection departments are unwilling to control pollution for the purpose of obtaining more revenue. Therefore, the actual amount of the water-pollutant discharge fee is embezzled and detained for other purposes. A fairly large amount of the pollutant fee falls outside of supervision, as the financial department is unable to acquire accurate information on the fee situation, which directly slows down the fee system’s development and lowers the efficiency of pollutant control. 3. Effectiveness of the Water- Pollutant Discharge-Fee System 3.1. System Performance Historically, the pollution discharge-fee program has been applied in both developed and developing countries worldwide. This market-based strategy achieved results on air, water, and solids pollution control in different degrees. In France and the Netherlands, the effluent charge is designed to raise revenue for water-pollution-control funding, ultimately achieving improvements in water quality (Tietenberg 1990). Wastewater dischargers in Germany are regulated to meet the minimum pollutant standard and pay for half of the standard-exceeding amount, while the related effluent charge is calculated per pollution unit and increased to control water pollution in the short term (Zhang and Xiong 2012). The practice in European countries explored and developed an independent and mature pollution-management approach involving a legal framework, a political mechanism, organization corporation, revenue supervision (Xiao 2003; Zhou 2006), which achieved significant results in water-pollution reduction. The mar- 12