China Policy Journal Volume 1, Number 1, Fall 2018 | Page 16

Water-Pollutant Discharge-Fee System in China ket-based instrument is an incentive by which to correct environmental externality and its implementation needs to be combined with related policies. The diversity of water resources in America determined the different states’ water policies. Empirical study support that water-pollution regulations had significant effects on firms’ production in water-polluting industries (Chakraborti 2016; Chakraborti and McConnell 2012; Rassier and Earnhart 2015; Shimshack and Ward 2008). The water policy and water quality mutually influence each other and a reverse effect has been observed in that the decline of water quality stimulates the stringency of the permitted discharge level, leading plants to consequently reduce their pollution emissions (Chakraborti 2016). Significant results in water-pollution control were achieved in developed countries that rely on well-defined property rights. The comments summarized that using market instruments and prices as the primary instruments to control pollution in developing countries is fragmented, due to the fact that the range of political, institutional, and administrative rules, practices, and processes is powerless in handling market-based strategies. In India, water governance is a challenge at almost all scales, whereby the states’ limited power not only weakens their capacity to solve transboundary water issues but also makes them powerless in the field of domestic water use and pollution (Chokkakula 2012). Evidence in Malaysia suggests the financial condition limits the investment in technical-abatement measures for water-pollution control in the sewage system, and that the lack of cooperation between governments and plants impedes water-quality improvement (Muyibi, Ambali, and Eissa 2008). Water and its derivative functions serve economic users, so that adopting a market instrument by which to guide water allocation and pollution issues is theoretically considered as a cost-effective approach. Therefore, the market paradigm was introduced and promoted in developed and transitioning countries, including China. To assess the market’s power on water governance in China, several questions have been addressed: How successful is the water-pollutant discharge-fee system in controlling water pollution? Which factors are responsible for its success? With regard to the first question, increasing empirical evidence demonstrates that the combination of the fee system and water-pollution regulations reduces pollution-intensive activity (Chen et al. 2018; Yuan, Jiang, and Bi 2010). Additionally, the collection of water-pollution discharge fees directly revealed the system’s degree of enforcement, which could be one of the main factors by which to assess its effectiveness. The national grand total pollution-fee amount from 1992 to 2014 is 237.59 billion RMB. The adjustment of the fee system in 2003 can be seen as a turning point: the growth rate of the pollutant discharge fee was below 10% until 2003, after which it doubled to reach its first peak at 17.68 billion RMB in 2008. It subsequently fluctuated due to the decreasing number of enterprises during the financial crisis. The total of the discharge-fee collection corre- 13