China Policy Journal Volume 1, Number 1, Fall 2018 | Page 14

Water-Pollutant Discharge-Fee System in China lution in a cost-effective way, there is widespread debate on whether the economic-incentive approach is more suitable than a command-and-control policy in developing countries (Barde 1994; Blackman and Harrington 2000; Panaiotov 1994; Motta, Huber, and Ruitenbeek 1999; Wolverton and West 2005). The advantages and disadvantages of such an approach have been analyzed in various situations. Bell and Russel (2002) indicate that developing countries do not possess the conditions for the implementation of market-based strategies. While constructive efforts are made to practice the fee system in China to control water pollution, even its stimulating effects are not that obvious and there exists deviation from the policy’s main purpose. Especially, the fee design impedes enterprises from reducing emissions: theoretically, the optimal charge level should be set at the point at which the marginal control cost equals the average marginal loss. If the pollutant-fee standard is higher than enterprises’ cost on pollutant reduction, the profit would drive enterprises to pursue technological innovation and device upgrades for emission reduction, or simply to choose to pay for pollutant emission rather than investing in pollution control, so that the incentives of the water-pollutant discharge-fee system would ultimately become ineffective. As difficult to define each pollutant’s marginal loss, the average cost on pollutant control has been adopted under technical assistance from World Bank’s research of The Design and Implementation of Pollution Discharge Fee in China in 1994, instead of calculating pollutants’ marginal treatment fee. Consequently, the cost of illegal discharge is lower than that of abiding by the law, which leads to the strange phenomenon of active contaminating payment versus passive improvement measures on pollution reduction. 2.2.2. Low Efficiency The process of collecting the pollutant discharge-fee met great resistance in its initial steps and significant percentages of enterprises eager to obtain higher profits consequently ignored environmental pollution, with some even refusing to pay the pollution fee, though investing in the visible short-term benefit program. Local environmental protection bureaus are understaffed, underequipped, and underpaid, thereby generating a poor system-implementation condition. The implementation of bank transfers appeared as a milestone in normalizing the pollution discharge-fee collection. As disputes between dischargers and executors mostly occur in the disconnection and noncompliance operation of the apply– verify procedure, false and concealed reports, lax law enforcement, and negotiated charges are common. Additionally, regulators set a single fee that was applied to all plants, with no regard for different levels of environmental tolerance or the demand of the regional-development function. In principle, the system not only lacks flexibility but also obstructs polluters’ adoption of abatement technologies. Furthermore, technical support is rarely mentioned and grossly limited in the system’s implementation. Disconnections within the water-pollutant discharge-fee system, including discharger registration, 11