World Food Policy WFP Volume 4, No. 2, Spring 2018 | Page 48

World Food Policy China’s second land reform was initiated through the household responsibility system (HRS) in 1978. The HRS reform dismantled the col- lective production, and distributed the collectively owned land to all vil- lage households based on number of people and labor in the household with the first contracted period of 15 years and then renewed for the other 30 years after the late 1990s (Lin, 1992; Brandt et al., 2002). The effects of HRS on the equitable distribution of land to farmers and ultimately on agricultur- al productivity, agricultural structural change and poverty alleviation have been obvious and well documented (Lin, 1992; Huang and Rozelle, 1996; McMillan et al., 1989; Jin et al., 2002). Moreover, the increase in agricultural productivity and food production re- sulted from HRS triggered a number of subsequent economic growth dy- namics, such as providing agricultural surplus labor for labor-intensive rural township and village enterprise (TVE) development in the mid-1980s (McK- innon, 1993), facilitating China’s over- all industrialization and ST since the early 1990s, and generating demand for the intermediate products of man- ufactures in the rest of economy (Qian and Xu, 1998). can be transferred from among farm- ers through land rental market, and emphasizing the further long run con- tract rights (or permanent) after end- ing the current 30 years contract in the late 2020s. With rising opportunities in off-farm employment and emerg- ing rural-urban migration, assisting smallholders to either move up or move out farming is critical. As the results of these institutional innovation, there has been a rapid emergence of middle and large farms in China (Huang and Ding, 2016). As rural households (or land contracted households) can decide whether to be “landlords” by renting out their land or expand their farm size, such achieving equity of land owner- ship distribution, increasing efficiency of land use, and facilitating rural trans- formation through either specializing in agricultural production or moving to off-farm employment. In the past six to seven decades, many developing countries in Asia have also pursued land reform but the re- sults are mixture. Land reform in Viet- nam reemphasized the essential of land reform in facilitating inclusive rural transformation. Vietnam followed suit with the land reform similar to that of China but even go beyond China by allowing farmers to buy, sell, and be- Recent land reforms have empha- queath land and to use land as collateral sized on securing land property rights with financial institutions for mortgag- and facilitating land use rights transfer. es. 6 The reforms have resulted in the These include ensuring the contracted significant rise in agricultural produc- rights for the original contracted house- tivity, farmer’s income and rural pover- holds, creating operation rights that ty reduction (Nguyen and Goletti, 2001; 6 In China, the right to buy and sell as well as use land as collateral with financial institutions for mortgages has not been implemented. 44