World Food Policy Volume 2, Number 1, Spring 2015 | Page 85

World Food Policy dairy farmers, as has been shown in India (Bhagowalia, Headey, and Kadiyala 2012), Rwanda (Pimkina et al. 2013), or Ethiopia (Hoddinott, Headey, and Dereje 2013). In addition, specializing in a commercial crop entails an income risk. An adverse event affecting the commercial crop may lead to a drop in household income and potentially a drop in food purchases. For example, in Kenya, in 1984, it was found that farming households living in irrigated areas had an income based on commercial rice and had poorer nutritional indicators (stunting) than households not living there with more diversified sources of incomes (Niemeijer and Hoorweg 1994). 3. Income uses: For example, extra income may be used for purposes other than buying food. In some countries and under different circumstances, it has been shown that the income elasticity of food consumption, or calorie consumption or nutriment intake might be null or even negative in certain cases. For example, Skoufias et al. (2009) found in Mexico, that “for the poorest households, the deficiency of total energy, protein, and zinc is not accompanied by a positive income elasticity.” 4. The person controlling the income: Income controlled by women is used more for food expenditure and has positive impacts on child nutrition (Marek 1992). Interventions that tend to reduce income controlled by women (even if the men get more income) therefore run the risk of producing negative impacts on nutrition (see risk 4). 5. Change in income regularity: A regular income, even small one, is used more for food than a larger but less regular one (Von Braun and Kennedy 1986; IYCN 2011). Strong income seasonality prevents households, who buy when prices are highest, from covering their annual needs. The period of higher prices also corresponds with peaks in the prevalence of water-related illnesses and workload peaks (Devereux and Longhurst 2010). Altogether, the ADIs whose main objective is to raise income of the poor/ farmers might not always end with the improvement in nutrition. One has to be aware that the additional income might be gained at the expenses of other sources of income (nonagricultural income) or resources (food) which might not be properly replaced. And that the use of additional income is not always directed to food expenditures nor adequate food, nor for the ones who are in deficit. 2. Risk of a mismatch in food availabilities and diversity: macro and “meso” (market chain, regional development) levels. B y focusing on certain specific products, ADIs affect the nature and quantity of available foods. They may have negative impacts on energy quantities (too much or not enough) and on available nutrients. This may be the case when agricultural policies encourage specialization at the expense of the availability and diversity of foodstuffs. 84