World Food Policy Volume 2, Number 1, Spring 2015 | Page 21

World Food Policy Selection and packing of fresh fruit, for example, if done off-farm, is counted in manufacturing and the workers deemed nonfarm employees, although in common parlance—and in the minds of economists unfamiliar with the details of national accounting—such an activity would be thought as part of the agricultural sector. Similarly, with development and an increasingly sophisticated food sector, wine production, pasteurized and ultrahigh-temperature (UHT) milk, cheese, eggs, and poultry processing, and other such activities, are taken out of the primary agriculture column in national accounts and classified as manufactures. And many activities producing intermediate inputs for farming—fertili zers, energy and traction, pesticides, and some machinery and labor services—which were formerly on-farm activities, are now provided by nonagricultural sectors. The more intensive is economic specialization in an economy, the smaller agriculture appears to be, certainly relative to the rest of the economy, simply as a matter of accounting definitions. This purely accounting-based perception of agriculture has reinforced the assessment found in a significant part of the economic development literature, especially related to Latin America, that the agricultural sector generates few positive externalities. The structuralist school (famously represented by Prebisch 1950; Singer 1957; Myrdal 1957), for example, contended that the farm sector contributed little to the rest of the economy via backward and forward linkages (purchases and sales). Without a significant contribution to the rest of the production system, various development experts concluded that the stimulation of the agricultural economy should be a low priority in the pursuit of economic development. Time has eroded confidence in this view, in large part due to the disappointing performance of the associated import-substitution strategy that accompanied it and due to the better understanding of the connection between improving farm productivity and poverty reduction in both rural and urban areas (see, for example, the extensive treatment in the World Bank’s World Development Report 2008: Agriculture for Development). More recently, research on the links between the sector with the rest of the economy have produced a body of evidence that agricultural growth would have significant multiplier effects, spreading through other sectors, beyond their direct contribution to GDP. In particular, research has shown quantitatively that acceleration in the growth of agricultural production in much of Latin America had a significantly positive effect on employment and wages of unskilled workers and through this process helped reduce rural poverty (see, for example, de Ferranti, et al. 2005; Bravo-Ortega and Lederman 2005; World Bank 2007). The purpose of this study is to present and apply a methodology to measure an “expanded agricultural VA,” i.e., a measure that incorporates the net impact of the primary sector on the VA of other sectors via backward and forward linkages. The following section discusses the importance of the strength of forward and backward linkages of primary agriculture to the rest of the economy, illustrating the linkages with evidence from the most recently available Chilean intermediate use matrix on which 20