The African Business Review May-Jun 2014 | Page 28

covering 96 countries for the period 1975-1998, he argues that « participatory political regimes are associated with significantly lower levels of aggregate economic instability ». According to him, the realization of political compromise is the channel of influence connecting democracy to macroeconomic stability. Democracies induce greater willingness to cooperate and compromise in the political sphere, generating greater stability as a result. One way in which democratic participation in politics can generate compromise is by altering preferences. As individuals meet and deliberate, they come to understand each other’s Macroeconomic pathologies such as poor management of external debt and consequent inflation are due to political practices governed by favouritism and rent-seeking. A democratic institutional environment characterized by participation, contestation and transparency can counteract these practices, thus reduce inflation. viewpoints, develop empathy, recognize the value of moderation, internalize the common interest, and de-emphasize narrow selfinterest. Liberal democracies entail constitutional rules that curtail the power of the majority to expropriate the minority. Separation of powers, specific minority protection clauses, and the rule of law are some of the more relevant mechanisms. Reducing the scope of redistributive action induces cooperative behaviour through two channels. First, winners cannot treat the losers as they please. Second, and less obviously, this fact in itself makes contending groups more willing to compromise ex ante, as it reduces both the perceived benefits of uncooperative behaviour and the perceived costs of cooperative behaviour (Rodrik, 2000). Lavigne (2006) has also granted to political factors an important role in explaining macroeconomic conditions. According to him, several countries, including emerging market economies are now facing the major challenge to carry out their tax adjustments policies.
According to the International Monetary Fund (2003, b), it appears that in 2002, the public debt of emerging countries has exceeded 70% of GDP. Lavigne (2006) considers that the success of fiscal adjustment plans in developed and developing countries is closely linked to the quality of the institutional framework, and particularly to the degree of democratization. There is some evidence that high levels of transfers and subsidies diminish the probability of successful adjustment in developing countries, and that legislative majorities improve the odds. In advanced countries, strong democratic institutions appear to increase the likelihood of avoiding situations of fiscal distress (Lavigne, 2006). Conflicts of interest between socioeconomic groups and social division act significantly on redistributive policies. These factors affect the level of subsidies and transfers of income policies. Havrylyshyn and Olding-Smee (2000) argue that spending on transfers and subsidies indicates the existence of rent-seeking vested interests and their assertion was supported by many authors (e.g., Alesina and Perotti; 1995; and Gupta et al., 2003). On the other hand, social division, resulting in income inequality and ethnic fragmentation intensifies conflicts redistribution.
Under these conditions, the State finds difficulty to establish effective 28 | The African Business Review tax policies adjustments which latter leads to macroeconomic imbalances and price increases. Berg and Sachs (1988) argue in this regard that income inequality is positively correlated with the level of public debt and Sachs (1989) argues that Latin American countries were unable to establish adjustment programs to control the debt crisis because of the rigidity of public consumption. Such rigidity was the result of the pressures exerted by socio-political interest groups who disallowed the government to establish tax reforms that adversely affect their economic interests. In a democracy, the effects of social division and conflict of interest are mixed. Democracy imposes legal constraints that facilitate the implementation of adjustment programs benefiting all the society. Fiscal discipline has been empirically linked to a number of institutional factors, including budgetary centralization, transparency, fiscal rules, and parliamentary procedures. In a more general sense, institutional quality is often proxied in the growth literature by an index of the rule of law, which evaluates the system of laws, conventions, and behaviour that support market economies, encourage investment, and protect public goods. It seems reasonable to expect that high institutional quality could foster a more efficient public sector and minimize corruption, translating into a better use of revenues and increased tax collection. It could also ensure that fiscal policy will not fall prey to vested interests. The quality of democratic institutions might also have a significant impact on fiscal consolidation (Lavigne, 2006). Two important conclusions can be derived after this literature review: Not only there is a negative causality between democracy and inflation but also, political participation is the deep determinant of inflation. Many macroeconomic aggregates, traditionally used as central variables in explaining the variability of inflation are themselves subject to the degree of democratization. We will demonstrate this theoretical assertion using an empirical model that evaluates the impact of democracy on inflation. Our model will incorporate, along with democracy index, economic and institutional control variables that are commonly considered as powerful determinants of inflation. This empirical study will however be preceded by the presentation of the democracy indicator that we will use as variable of interest in our model. Presentation of the Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi (2012) democracy index It should first be noted that the empirical literature has expe