Military Review English Edition January-February 2014 | Page 38

Overall, FM 3-24 says the state is intrinsically good, and more is better; that which is outside the state and those disinclined to submit to the comprehensive rule of the state deviant. In the absence of any qualifying commentary, FM 3-24 adds up to a directive to pursue the Western-ideal-type state: maximal sovereignty and autonomy, and deeply penetrative, solely responsible for managing social relations and resources. Sociopolitical consciousness and international recognition are assumed. State and Society in Afghanistan According to FM 3-24, violence and instability in Afghanistan is a product of the Afghan state’s deviation from the Western-ideal type. Yet, despite significant periods of stability, Afghanistan has never had this type of state. Anthropologist Thomas Barfield compares the Western-ideal type to American cheese: consistent and dominant throughout all of Afghanistan’s territory, without gaps. Successful Afghan states, such as Musahiban dynasty’s from 1929 to 1978, Barfield observes, have been more akin to Swiss cheese, where gaps and inconsistencies are essential features of the product.17 Attempts to construct an American cheese-type state have not stabilized the country. Rather, they have met resistance and have more often than not failed. This Swiss cheese model scores differently than Western states among Nettl’s conceptual variables. It resembles Migdal’s mélange, where his basic state capacities—social penetration and regulation, and resource extraction and appropriate—are much reduced or distributed across nonstate actors. The state, as Barfield explains, traditionally has been the domain of particular elite lineages and not accessible to the masses. Authorities and territory could be transferred through inheritance, gifts, and peace agreements. The periphery did not participate in the contest for control over the state. The local leaders could keep local power so long as they submitted to the center.18 Although limited participation in the state amounted to a certain amount of state autonomy, the state was not entirely sovereign over remote areas.19 It minimally penetrated society in these parts, and allowed others to regulate social relations and extract and appropriate resources. In Barfield’s words, these areas did not need to be “ruled directly or subjected to the same style of government” as more productive areas. The 36 state could use economic, political, and coercive inducements to keep these areas inline without administering them directly. This is precisely the opposite of the counterinsurgency field manual’s recommendation to extend the government. Rather than bringing the state to the people, each left the other alone. The relationship between stability and limitations on state authority is traced to Ahmed Shah Durrani, who in 1747 became the first person to rule the territory that is now Afghanistan. Although Durrani spent lavishly on his military, his state was not the single dominant actor throughout Afghanistan. For example, he was obliged to supply leaders of his own Durrani tribe with cash or land in exchange for about two-thirds of his troops. These irregular troops were loath to spend more than a year in service.20 In addition to tax exemptions, the state did not interfere with Durrani tribal social practices or other resources. In non-Durrani areas, the state extracted heavy taxes but no troops. As in Durrani areas, it left social regulation to others.21 In sum, the Ahmed Shah Durrani, 18th century illustration. January-February 2014 MILITARY REVIEW