International Journal on Criminology Volume 3, Number 1, Spring 2015 | Page 57

International Journal on Criminology When crime rates go up, marginal benefits of protective measures increase and at a certain point outweigh marginal costs. Potential victims will be ready to invest in security. When levels of crime prevention rise, the costs/benefits ratio of offending becomes less favorable. At some point offending starts to become economically unattractive. At this juncture crime rates will start to fall (Van Dijk 2010, 2). Citing the work of Graham Farrell, Nick Tilley, Andromachi Tseloni, and Jen Mailley on the “security hypothesis” in terms of vehicle thefts and a study by Ben Vollaard and Jan van Ours on burglaries, Van Dijk notes that: Several studies have demonstrated that the fall in car thefts has indeed been largely caused by in-built security (e.g. Farrell et al. 2008). In a recent study, Ben Vollaard and Van Ours (2010) of Tilburg University assessed the effects of legislation that made state-of-the-art household security mandatory in houses built after 1999 in The Netherlands. He shows that burglary victimization rates in newly built houses were a quarter lower than in the older ones. There were no signs of displacement to other neighborhoods in the city. The implementation of the new legislation alone has prevented the commission of 10,000 burglaries (… from 2001 to 2009) (Van Dijk 2010, 2). The change in the trend of domestic burglary with forced entry that occurred in 2008, and the sharp increases that followed in metropolitan France, Belgium, and Germany after a period of several years of distinct decline, appear to weaken the hypothesis according to which Jan Van Dijk’s process of “responsive securitization” “may well have been the main driver of the crime falls.” Analysis of the characteristics of the increase of burglary in Belgium and metropolitan France offers the possibility of envisaging a “hypothesis of professionalization” that does not necessarily call into question the origin of the previous drop, especially because it takes inspiration from the theories mentioned, the “crime opportunity theory” and the “routine activity theory,” and also from the theory of rational choice. Motivated by the lesser penal risk of nonviolent burglary and by the rising price of gold, the arrival of new actors working within the context of organized crime may have changed the balance of the crime market. Existing protective measures would no longer be enough to protect homes due to the use of more effective methods of operation. The pertinence of responsive securitization at a given moment does not exclude that the behavior of actors can subsequently change. In the equation determining the level of victimization rates, the impact of victim response can be reduced by perpetrators adapting their techniques. It is therefore possible that we are now engaged in a new cycle of responsive securitization that responds to a much more elaborate form of burglary with forced entry than before. The existence of an annual victimization surveys in France should now allow multiple empirical verifications related to this subject. 56