Gold Magazine June - July 2013, Issue 27 | Page 36
OPINION
The Safest Way
to Let Banks Fail
Imposing losses on creditors won’t
be enough in a systemic crisis
T
he European crisis – and especially this
spring’s events in Cyprus – has put the
spotlight on a once-taboo question: Can a
major bank be allowed to fail?
Looking back at recent financial history, it is quite
difficult to find examples of fully-fledged bank failures in which losses have been forced upon creditors.
Instead there are manifold examples of banks being
rescued, either with or without public support. Such
rescues have led to the perception that certain institutions are “too big to fail” or “too interconnected to
fail.”
These propositions alter the incentives of bank
owners and lenders. Moral hazard has become entrenched in the system.
Why have banks not been allowed to fail? One
factor is path-dependence: By not letting banks fail in
the past, policymakers face strong pressure not to let
banks fail in the future. Time-inconsistency also plays
a role: The rewards from letting banks fail – reduced
moral hazard chief among them – lie in the future,
whereas the costs – financial destabilization and voter
outrage – are imminent.
But the biggest obstacle is simply that, for now, the
markets do not expect big banks to be allowed to fail.
There is no concept more fundamental in economics and finance than expectations. When unexpected
events occur, disorder can set in instantly.
This is why the initial agreement to haircut Cypriot
depositors caused such unrest. It was jarring enough
that deposits – perceived as the safest of all forms of
credit – would be hit under the plan. But to hit deposits below the insured level of €100,000 was seen
as crossing a red line. Cyprus was – unfortunately, to
my mind – interpreted as the beginning of an unexpected regime change in how bank failures are dealt
with in Europe.
Hence the importance of the European Commission’s Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive,
which seeks to establish a pan-European framework
to allow for orderly bank resolution. As the European
Parliament’s lead negotiator on the directive, I have
been studying the Cypriot case and other examples
of bank failures quite intensively. A few points seem
fundamental to me:
First, bank failures must be managed as predictably as possible. One cannot alter the rules of the
game without adequate prior notice. Even the most
well-considered line of action will have adverse con-
Bank failures
must be
managed as
predictably as
possible
By Gunnar
Hökmark
sequences on market and depositor confidence if it is
not carried out according to clear ex-ante principles.
Formally secured investments such as insured deposits
and covered bonds must be fully protected and exempt from the scope of any bail-in.
Second, the bail-in tool is complex to implement.
It has many benefits, not least that bank creditors will
be more certain of the riskiness of their investments.
If the markets have been prepared for it, bailing in
creditors will help resolve banks without the use of
taxpayers’ money. But bailing in creditors in large
volumes carries risks of contagion, especially when
applied to banks whose creditors are, to a large extent,
depositors.
Third and last, a bail-in alone will probably not
be sufficient in systemic crises. When the payment
system – the most basic infrastructure of our modern
economies – is in peril, government has a responsibility to act. Not because it is desirable, but because the
alternative is far worse.
If our new bank-resolution rules do not allow for
government intervention as a last resort, then future
resolutions will be more or less solely dependent on
a bail-in. In the heat of a systemic crisis, this might
cause more p roblems than it solves, thereby reducing
the probability that bail-in is used at all.
Hence the best framework for dealing with a bank
in severe stress should allow for both kinds of tools.
When a bank is taken into temporary public ownership, for instance, moral hazard should simultaneously
be addressed by wiping out previous shareholders and
bailing in holders of unsecured debt to the largest feasible extent, with uninsured deposits being preferred
in the hierarchy.
If markets know that government can intervene
to contain chaos while also imposing losses on shareholders and creditors, then the application of bail-in
will be more credible compared to a scenario in which
bail-in alone is the only option.
Against this background, I am very satisfied that
the European Parliament’s Economic and Monetary
Affairs Committee backed my main proposals when
we voted on the text of the directive. Once European
finance ministers have reached a common agreement,
we can initiate final negotiations on a joint legislative
text that will enter into force on January 1, 2015.
Done as outlined above, the forthcoming framework for bank resolution can both reduce moral hazard and enhance systemic stability.
info: Gunnar Hökmark is a Swedish member of the European Parliament, vice president of the European People’s Party Group and rapporteur for the Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive.
34 Gold THE INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT, FINANCE & PROFESSIONAL SERVICES MAGAZINE OF CYPRUS
opinions_hokmark&evgeniou.indd 34
10/06/2013 18:05