European Policy Analysis Volume 2, Number 1, Spring 2016 | Page 56

Second Tier, Second Thoughts Funds (NAPF), representing 400 providers, 1 trillion pound of invested capital and 16 million employee contracts, fears an irritation of the British market for occupational pensions if the relatively recent auto-enrolment products30 were defined as being part of the 3rd pillar by EIOPA and were the Commission and regulated as PPPs accordingly (ibid., gen. com. 20). The Netherlands’ Ministry of Finance, to include a voice from a third of the four big markets for occupational pensions, underscores that the 2nd pillar, which in the national definition covers all pension plans with an employer contribution accounts for 43% of total pensions paid there, and that its national regulation significantly differs from that of the 3rd pillar (EIOPA 2014a, gen. com. 21). Subtext: And we want it to stay that way. Pensions Europe, an umbrella group for occupational pension lobbyists, summarily calls for schemes “linked to a current or previous employment relationship” (EIOPA 2014a, gen. com.) to remain outside the scope of EIOPA’s PPP agenda.31 So clearly the tussles about pillar definitions and EIOPA’s mandate for a 2nd tier PPP have an element of turf war about market segments to them. Yet the second group of stakeholders just mentioned, the one questioning the usefulness of the pillar metaphor and its associated border fences, put forward an argument phrased spot on by the (UK-based) Investment Management Association: “[T]he distinction in reality between pure DC funded arrangements (e.g., Pillar 1 bis, Pillar 2 occupational and Pillar 3 personal) lies often in governance and distribution arrangements. Fundamentally, the pension arrangements themselves may not look very different from one another.” (EIOPA 2014a, gen. com. 18). This raises the question how different regimes can legitimately be applied to essentially identical pension products to be found across all three pillars. Of course, within each pillar they are combined with and/ or compete with distinct other products, but the parting clearly exhibits an artificial element. For example, if investment into a pension fund falls into 1st pillar bis, its tax treatment will often receive 1st pillar privileges, while the same product is treated less favorably in pillar three. So the axis of (non)discrimination between member states is complemented by the axis between pillars, and thus calls for harmonization (like the one by ABI for a single pensionable age, cf. EIOPA 2014a, com. 318) acquire a multidimensional character. 30 “These [DC] schemes are established by the employer but take the form of a contract between the individual saver and a pension provider.” (EIOPA 2014a, gen. com. 20). 31 In Question 6, EIOPA explicitly asked stakeholders whether they believe that a “personal pension contract […] chosen by an employer” (EIOPA 2013) should be considered a PPP. Sixty per cent of those answering this question do not think so. Ten per cent have no firm view or feel that the crucial distinction is actually whether an employer involved is giving any sort of guarantee (for the latter view cf. EIOPA 2014a, com. 154). The coalition of those 30% who are in favor of including employer-chosen pension plans into EIOPA’s PPP activities encompasses large pension fund and insurance associations from big national markets—and the Commission’s already mentioned brainchild FSUG; an alliance that is as typical as it is problematic, since the Commission thus creates the impression of including consumer interests with a vehicle of its own creation. 56