European Policy Analysis Volume 2, Number 1, Spring 2016 | Page 54

Second Tier, Second Thoughts like sustainability tests for group pensions or the design of disclosure documents.25 The remainder of stakeholder comments (EIOPA 2014a, com. 81, 82, 85, 86, 89, 94, 98) admonishes EIOPA (and the Commission) about overlaps and potential contradictions between already existing regulatory strands. These are mainly an effect of the dichotomy of product and provider regulation. If, for example, a pension fund and an insurance company offered the same pan-European PPP, under existing rules, they would fall under different regulatory regimes, and the 2nd tier could add a second layer for both, possibly rendering the playing field both uneven and overly bureaucratic.26 When directly asked (in Question 24) whether EIOPA should focus on either product or provider rules, however, surprisingly few stakeholders give an opinion. None favors a sole focus on providers, four think EIOPA should only address products, and six suggest a two-pronged approach.27 Sometimes different stakeholders disagree less about regulatory options than about assumed market dynamics, which can be illustrated with two examples regarding EIOPA’s Question 9 (about provider-specific prudential obstacles to a more integrated market). While Groupe Consultatif urges EIOPA not to include any guarantees in a standardized PPP (EIOPA 2014a, com. 235), the Bulgarian Association of Supplementary Pension Security Companies (EIOPA 2014a, com. 231) opines that such provisions would turn out meaningless in a more competitive market, because market forces would generate pressure toward very attractive terms for consumers. In the second example, market dynamics are argued to be much weaker or even absent by one of the stakeholders. The Luxembourg-based Association of International Life Offices (EIOPA 2014a, com. 225), on the one hand, points out that death benefits “in an insured PPP” might probably constitute “obstacles to transfer to or from a noninsurer”. The Association of the Luxembourg Fund Industry, on the other hand, surmises that “insurers may not seek to offer personal pension products in a systematic manner throughout the European Union” (EIOPA 2014a, com. 226). Were EIOPA—in the interest of nondiscrimination—to define a rather broad class of 2nd tier PPP that gives several options to customers, some stakeholders insist on the regulatory setting of a default option (EIOPA 2014a, com. 494 and 498). This would, of course, reintroduce official favoritism of certain providers through the back-door, if only in the shape of a more or less powerful 25 Admittedly, though, it might be a challenge to devise unified a pan-European disclosure document, and to comply with it might be much easier for large providers with strong, internationally versed legal divisions. Thus, ironically concentration processes might be catalyzed in a market where the actual regulatory goal is to avoid cluster risks. 26 The German Insurance Association provides a very simple, if somewhat one-sided solution: “we suggest taking the insurance regulation as a benchmark which includes PPPs provided by insurers and sufficiently reflects the true risk profiles of the providers” (EIOPA 2014a, com. 90). 27 The numbers are nearly identical concerning question 25 about “same risk—same rules—same capital” (on this issue, see Section 2), and the main divide here is whether the risks covered by different existing PPPs are fundamentally similar or not. 54