European Policy Analysis Volume 2, Number 1, Spring 2016 | Page 23

European Policy Analysis Switzerland’s climate policy on the national level has been almost exclusively focusing on climate mitigation for decades, Switzerland elaborated funding scheme solutions that would incentivize the private sector to promote international adaptation measures with their international partners in the EIG group. The policies and related negotiations we investigate in this article took place at two different points in time: the design of the policy on the national level occurred around the year 2005, when Switzerland first revised the CO2 act and introduced the tax in combination with the tradable permits and the climate penny. The international policy formulation during the COP in Copenhagen and Cancun happened in 2009 and 2010. Seen from a temporal perspective, the national position could have impacted the position of the Swiss delegation also in international negotiations. As this was not the case, the question arises whether the divergence in position is a consequence of divergent negotiation topics at the two levels, or of different negotiation cultures within the Swiss political elite on the national and the international levels. Below, we develop those thoughts and outline some theoretical arguments which could account for the difference between Switzerland’s national and international position in climate change policy. and countries (Jones and Jenkins-Smith 2009; Gilardi 2010; Kay 2011). However, those influences are not limited to the products of policymaking, but also hold for political bargaining and decisionmaking processes. Although several theories and frameworks focus on actors and their role in order to explain such mutual influence mechanisms among different processes (Hooghe and Marks 2003; Marks, Hooghe, and Blank 1996; Sabatier and Jenkins-Smith 1993), there are two diverging views on how much actors might coordinate actions across levels. For instance, in multilevel governance and the “ecology of games”, actors are involved in different “games” or “arenas” at the same time (Dutton, Schneider, and Vedel 2012; Lubell, Henry, and McCoy 2010). Those “games” can be characterized by very heterogeneous institutions and rules, which is why the same actors tend to behave differently and defend divergent interests (Moravcsik 1993; Lubell et al. 2012). Putnam (1988) also argues that actors involved in foreign policymaking produce different policy outputs in the absence of domestic pressures and vice-versa; but this is not true in twolevel games where both spheres are entangled. In such “overlapping or nested subsystems ” actors are functionally interdependent, which might result in coordination and feedback from one system to the other (Jones and JenkinsSmith 2009; Zafonte and Sabatier 1998). Finally, also Lisowski (2002) applies the Theory two-level games metaphor for US climate egarding policy outputs, there politics and its repudiation of the Kyoto is convincing evidence of policy Protocol and convincingly demonstrates learning, diffusion, and spill-over how President George Bush Jr. legitimizes effects across policy levels, domains, his international approach with domestic evidences. R 23