Creating Profit Through Alliances - business models for collaboration E-book | Page 93

handful of people. If any of these should leave the company or lose interest, this may jeopardise the collaboration. The smaller company may also lack the strength or scope to go along with new developments or market changes, which can also devalue the collaboration. These issues generally play a role if the difference between the companies, in terms of turnover, staffing and size, exceeds a factor of 10. This is not an absolute figure. Doing business with an autonomous business unit of a large multinational can be very like doing business with a small company. And a hightech company with 20 people on the payroll will often be a much stronger partner than a production company with 20 employees. As a „standard‟ example, consider smaller technology firms that may have just one or a few products, but with which they truly contribute something new to the market. Such companies often consist of the founders plus a few others, and they lack the size and skills to commercially exploit their product. Here, collaborating with a multinational is an obvious option: it gives the larger company access to technology, and gives the smaller company access to the market. However, the companies' interests may differ. For the technology firm, the product for which the alliance is set up may yield the lion's share of their turnover. For the multinational, the added revenue may basically be negligible. Certainly if the manager (at the multinational) who made the deal leaves or makes an internal career move, the technology company may wind up in an impasse: the exploitation rights have been sold but are not generating any income, due to the larger company's lack of interest. From the smaller company's perspective, the best solution would be to make clear arrangements about interim payments and the use of the provided expertise. Every bit of knowledge transfer should be met with immediate reward, at least partly. This reward can be payment for a patent or an hourly tariff for the deployment of experts. In addition, a success fee may be arranged for every successful market introduction. The smaller company cannot force its partner to market a product containing its expertise. For that reason it makes sense to couple any exclusive agreement to a 'shelf clause'. This means that, if the product development does not result in a market introduction within a predetermined period (that is, is shelved) or does not achieve a certain sales volume, then the smaller party is free to offer its patents and experience to another party. That this is something to take seriously was a lesson learnt by the British smartphone company Sendo, that entered into an alliance with Microsoft in 2000. Sendo had advanced quite a way in developing a telephone suitable for Internet applications, the Z100, and Microsoft was developing software for it. The agreement stated that the Z100 would be developed further jointly, and that Microsoft would receive part of the profit. In 2001 Microsoft invested 12 million dollars in development, and was entitled to appoint a supervisor to the Sendo board. From that momen