China Policy Journal Volume 1, Number 1, Fall 2018 | Page 65

China Policy Journal cultural or educational, are very often non-excludable and non-rival, which means that their exchange on the market is impossible. Second, many aspects of the wellbeing that an individual receives from nature are not measurable, and some elements of the total value of nature to humans may not even be observable. A good example is the non-use value of the environment and resources: simply knowing the “existence” of good functions of the ecological system and the assurance of their provision to future generations can create satisfaction that is not associated with any observable consumption behaviors. Previous studies have proven that the non-use value may occupy a high percentage in the total value of the environment. Wattage and Mardle (2008) found that the proportion of aggregated preferences related to the use value to conserve a wetland ecosystem was 55.3%, compared with 44.7% for the non-use value. Sander, Walsh, and Loomis (1990) concluded that the use values (e.g., irrigation, swimming, fishing, and tourism) of the 15 rivers in the state of Colorado in the United States were only approximately 1/5 of their total value; the other 4/5 of the value was principally non-use value. We can distinguish five categories of ecological goods and service (EGS) valuation methods. The first consists of the methods that are based on market prices; they only assess the direct use value of EGS referenced to their market value. The second category consists of the methods based on costs, which estimate the EGS value by the cost of avoided damage or the replacement cost of ecosystem losses. The third category consists of the revealed preference methods (e.g., hedonic price, travel costs), which are based on consumer preferences that are revealed by their behavior in an existing market. An example of this method, the hedonic price, considers the complementarity between air quality within an area and house prices (Bateman et al. 2011; Desaigues and Point 1993; Malër 1974) and uses the increase of the house value due to the better air quality as an assessment of the economic value of the better air quality, all else being equal. The fourth category consists of methods based on stated preference (e.g., contingent valuation, discrete choice experiments), which measure the value of EGS via simulated markets to identify survey respondent trade-offs between the price to pay (or compensation to accept) and improvement (or degradation) of the environment. Finally, the benefit transfer methods involve estimating the value of EGS for a target site using existing valuation estimates from primary studies for similar sites that explicitly use one of the four preceding method categories (Navrud and Ready 2007). Each method has its advantages and disadvantages. The measure of cost/market price is relatively easy to use but only focuses on marketable characteristics of the ecosystem. Revealed preference methods depend on observable consumer behaviors in markets for complementary goods and can thus only measure the direct- and indirect-use values of EGS. Benefit transfer is a secondary method that ex- 62