China Policy Journal Volume 1, Number 1, Fall 2018 | Page 64

Payment for Ecological Services and River Transboundary Pollution Using GIS water quality panel data from 321 monitoring stations across Brazil as well as jurisdictional boundary modification data for 5,500 Brazilian counties, Lipscomb and Mobarak (2008) studied whether water quality across jurisdictional boundaries deteriorates due to the concentration of polluting activities near a river’s exit from a jurisdiction. Their results confirmed that within a 5-kilometer distance from a boundary, pollution increased by 2.3% for every kilometer closer a river was to the exit border. In addition to the river transboundary pollution cases, transboundary air pollution has been studied. One interesting example is Helland and Whitford (2003). Motivated by anecdotal evidence suggesting that local regulators were more lenient in their treatment of polluters when the incidence of pollution partially fell on those outside the state, this paper examined a transboundary air pollution spillover incidence that occurred in the US and revealed significantly higher toxic chemical levels in border counties. 3. Standards for Payment of Ecological Services For the PES mechanism, the most important question is how to set reasonable payment standards for the affected ecological services. By “selling” the ecological services provided by environment protectors to the beneficiaries, this mechanism aims to generate funds to increase the conservation benefits perceived by the environmental protectors and therefore reinforces their incentives to protect the environment and resources. Following this logic, we should expect the payment of the PES mechanism to be higher than or at least equal to the conversation cost and/ or the opportunity cost of the existing commercial development projects to which the environmental protectors face. The larger the gap is between the perceived benefit and the cost, the more room there is for negotiation between environmental service providers and beneficiaries and the higher the probability is to bring welfare increases for both sides and to realize effective environmental protection. However, the difficulties in assigning pertinent monetary values to affected ecological services are numerous. Although natural environments represent one of the cornerstones of the human environment and offer essential goods and services for human survival and well-being, their integration into the economic system has proven to be very complex. The process to include the total economic value of nature in a neoclassical logic requires the encounter of two fundamental elements: the physical, biotic and abiotic components of nature on the one hand and the individual's view of these elements on the other. If it is reasonable to use the wellbeing that the individual obtains from these natural components, two aspects of the difficulty of putting a dollar value to such wellbeing remain: First, not all the wellbeing obtained by an individual is exchangeable in a market. The response of the nature to the multitude of human needs, whether aesthetic, 61