China Policy Journal Volume 1, Number 1, Fall 2018 | Page 52

Assessing the Implementation of Local Emission Trading Schemes in China lem of low-level pricing happens at other existing ETSs as well. As a comparison, the EUA price in EU-ETS during Phase II (2008–2012) was about 23.64 $/ton CO 2 e on average (Daskalakis 2013). Nonetheless, it decreases to a low level in Phase III (2013–2020). For instance, the EUA price was only about 8$/ton CO 2 e in April 2015 and about 6$/ton CO 2 e in April 2016 (World Bank 2015; 2016), which were similar to the level of the CEA price in Shenzhen ETS at that time. The low-level economic incentive from ETS was not able to encourage the regulated enterprises to invest in mitigation technologies in China (Yang, Li, and Zhang 2016). The enterprises rather considered participation in ETS as an approach to enhance public image and the ties with governments (Yang, Li, and Zhang 2016). However, a market-based policy instrument like ETS tends to be more acceptable by enterprises than the traditional command-and-control approach (Liu et al. 2013). Also, ETS mobilized a large number of business actors (emitters and intermediaries), local officials and researchers to work on low-carbon strategies and activities. The cooperative governance network constructed during the process is likely to be necessary and more cost efficient for long-run emission reduction in China. The price values of CEA and the level of trading activities vary across the ETS pilots, which is reasonable considering the differences in policy design, local governments’ political will and local economic context. Among the city-level ETSs, Chongqing and Tianjin are not so market-oriented, with lower CEA prices and less active transactions. Loose enforcement, the oversupply of allowances and emphasis on local economic interests can be the reasons. An implication is that even though China is keen to develop the national ETS, it may work better in some regions than others at the local level. When investigating into the Granger causality from energy prices to CEA prices, the findings varied among local ETSs, because of local differences in market dynamics of CEA and energy resources. We found no significant Granger causality from energy price changes to CEA price changes in the two provincial level ETSs, Hubei, and Guangdong. Regarding the city-level ETSs, we found a Granger causality from oil price changes to CEA price changes in Beijing. And, there was a positive effect of oil price changes on CEA price changes with the one-week lag. It implied a short-term substitution of oil with coal which is cheaper and more carbon-intensive. In Shanghai, we found a Granger causality from coal price changes to CEA price changes in Shanghai. And the coal price changes had a negative short-run effect on the CEA price changes, indicating that an increase in coal price drives a move away from coal toward less carbon-intensive fuels (e.g. natural gas or oil). It was also found that there was a positive short-run effect of LNG price changes on Shanghai CEA price changes, which is also consistent with the substitution theory. The scale of the short-run effect of LNG price is smaller than that of coal price. This is because the coal consumption makes up a larger portion of the energy consumption so that the chang- 49