China Policy Journal Volume 1, Number 1, Fall 2018 | Page 164

Chronic Noncompliance and Ineffective Enforcement in Guangzhou more easily caught and harsh penalties thereafter imposed. The reporting of illegal air pollution, on the other hand, was relatively more difficult to penalize. The main reason for such differences might be explained by the low visibility of air pollution and the difficulty of detecting and verifying it. Our findings have confirmed the arguments in the regulatory literature derived from the experiences of both industrialized and industrializing countries, namely, that the sole reliance on either the formal government enforcement or the civilian enforcement cannot effectively ensure corporate compliance with the environmental regulations. Only with an effective combination of formal and informal enforcement mechanisms can any environmental compliance regime ensure the compliant behavior of firms. As shown by the case of Guangzhou, the central government’s increased emphasis on pollution control and the continued strengthening of environmental legislation have led to enhanced law enforcement and tougher penalties against illegal polluters at the local level. From 2010, more polluting firms were subjected to political implementation of environmental rules jointly conducted by the EPBs and BODIs and forced to permanently shut down. The past few years have also witnessed the development of public participation in environmental regulation and this has led to the increased detection of environmental violations and more intrusive law enforcement activities launched by the government. However, the positive correlation between enhanced law enforcement and the decrease in chronic noncompliance with environmental rules was more likely to be observed among small polluters. The sheer scale and the elusive nature of the environmental violations by these polluters used to create major obstacles for effective law enforcement. Illegal emissions committed by small factories were extremely difficult to catch and punish by government enforcement agencies which were seriously undermanned and more preoccupied by the regulation of the larger pollution sources. For large polluting firms (mostly SOEs, as well as some privately owned ones), although they are more visible and thus subjected to more frequent and intense monitoring and inspections conducted by the government law enforcement agencies, insignificant penalties, relative to their compliance costs or economic scale, make it more attractive for them to evade the various laws. As for small polluting firms, although the penalties for them are significant relative to their size and scale, the probability of being caught in noncompliance remains low mainly due to the shortage of manpower and resources of the grassroots regulatory forces, and many would simply choose to take the risk; and, even when they are caught, it is also neither difficult nor economically devastating to simply abandon the business and evade the punishment. The opening-up and expansion of political space for more involvement by public monitoring and NGO-led litigation is expected to make noncompliance by polluting firms more costly. Through the experience of Guangzhou, 161